Gift expenditures grow swiftly in rural China and may adversely affect people's welfare. While gift-giving helps to maintain social status and connections, gift competition may create a predicament: people must spend more and more to "keep up with the Joneses." As a result, the escalating gift expenses crowd out spending on other important consumption and become increasingly burdensome to people in rural areas, particularly to the poor.
A wedding ceremony in a rural area of Guizhou (Source: Xi Chen).
In many developing countries, gift-giving plays an important role in maintaining social and economic bonds. In rural China, gift exchanges are integral to guanxi, the strong social connections that affect many aspects of everyday life, including the harvest, house building, personal finance, and school choice. Gifts serve as a kind of quasi-credit or insurance used to build reciprocal relationships and improve public perception. Gift-giving is also key to maintaining social status; many people in rural China engage in conspicuous consumption to acquire and protect their rank in local society (Brown, Bulte, and Zhang, 2011). As a result, gift-giving accounts for a large share of living expenditures in rural areas. This burden is growing: the gift-to-income ratio in China is now at 10 percent and climbing.
Figure 1: Annualized growth in per capita income, consumption, and gift spending by administrative villages.
(Source: Generated by authors based on their four wave Guizhou survey.)
New research conducted in a range of villages shows that this gift-giving trend has negative impacts. It is competitive and increases inequality, stresses household budgets, and undermines overall welfare.
In rural China, gift-giving often becomes a kind of race to assert one’s societal status. Gifts are not seen merely as expressions of generosity or altruism but are constantly assessed; that is, the value of one’s gift is compared with the value of gifts given by others. People are more likely to be perceived as true friends if their gifts are more valuable than the average gifts given by others. This creates a predicament, popularly referred to in the Western world as “keeping up with the Joneses.” In other words, people must spend more and more on gifts in order to keep up with the rising prices of gifts given by neighbors.
Ultimately, these escalating gift expenses may crowd out spending on other important consumption items. Between 2004 and 2011, gift expenditures in sampled villages grew by more than 30 percent per year while villagers’ annual nominal income grew by around 20 percent (see Figure 1). Since households can only receive gifts when hosting major social events, such as a wedding ceremony or funeral, they have to be “net givers” for a long period of time without any compensating inflow of gifts, which may result in liquidity problems. To make up that shortfall, families tighten their belts by reducing expenditures elsewhere, borrowing to finance gift-giving, and even practicing risky behaviors like donating blood plasma in exchange for cash rewards.
Not only does this competition distort the allocation of income between gifts and other consumption, the rising value of gifts received does not compensate for the costs associated with gifts given for other reasons. There may be “deadweight losses” associated with gifts (Waldfogel, 1993) caused by a mismatch between the preferences of the giver and recipient. For example, in the context of rural China, a welfare cost will occur because many in-kind gifts are overly “luxurious” — gift givers buy expensive food and commodities that are different from the items that they would purchase for their own consumption.
These problems have serious implications for well-being, particularly for poor families. As shown in the left and central panels of the following graph, low-income and middle-income households’ subjective well-being was negatively correlated with higher gift expenses. However, the giving competition has less impact on the well-being of the rich; the association between gift expenses and subjective welfare is very weak for high-income groups as shown in the right panel of the figure. The welfare effects are heterogeneous because the escalating gift spending squeezes consumption of other goods, which is particularly costly for the poor (who have a higher marginal utility of consumption). Meanwhile, reciprocal relations are especially vital for relatively poor households, who have fewer mechanisms to smooth consumption in times of temporary hardship. However, poor households may respond more to gift competition than the rich. In another study, Chen and Zhang (2012) show that gift competition has even resulted in stunting the growth of and causing low birthweight of children born to low-income mothers when conceived in the months with greater numbers of weddings and funerals in rural villages.
Figure 2: The (heterogeneous) effect of escalating gift expenses on subjective well-being.
People give gifts that aim to boost public perception and to maintain or improve their everyday reciprocal relationships. Yet, the net outcome of this activity, especially for the poor, results in lower overall well-being. Is there a way out of this trap? Potential efficiency gains and distributional benefits might be achieved if some policies, such as the restriction of extravagant weddings and funerals for government officials and communist party members, are introduced in order to solve the coordination problem. Once the elites stop the practice of lavish ceremonies, the ordinary people may follow and reduce the pressure for “keeping up with the Jones”.
(Erwin Bulte, Wageningen University and Utrecht University; Ruixin Wang, Harbin Institute of Technology, Shenzhen; Xiaobo Zhang, Peking University and International Food Policy Research Institute.)
References
Brown, Philip H., Erwin Bulte, and Xiaobo Zhang, 2011. “Positional Spending and Status Seeking in Rural China,” Journal of Development Economics 96: 139–149.
https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0304387810000593
Bulte, Erwin, Ruixin Wang, and Xiaobo Zhang, 2018. “Forced Gifts: The Burden of Being a Friend,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 155: 79-98.
https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0167268118302166?via%3Dihub
Chen, Xi, and Xiaobo Zhang, 2012. "Costly Posturing: Relative Status,
Ceremonies and Early Child Development." IFPRI Discussion Paper #01206.
http://ebrary.ifpri.org/cdm/ref/collection/p15738coll2/id/127126
Waldfogel, Joel, 1993. “The Deadweight Loss of Christmas,” American Economic Review 83 (5): 1328-1336.
https://www.jstor.org/stable/2117564?seq=1#metadata_info_tab_contents